Monday, March 30, 2009

Re-Post Number 3: "A WPA in 2008: 1 Million? Or 4 Million?" (Aug 09, 2007)

Note: In this re-post, which follows directly from the second, I tie the issue of direct job creation policy to a larger political argument I have with certain members of the Democratic Party about negotiating strategy. In short, I think that one of the problems with the Democratic Party at present is that, in order to seem "reasonable" and "moderate," we propose legislation that gets us 50% of what we want, and then we end up with 25% or nothing. I believe that we need to start with 200% of what we want to end up with 100%.
-------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Hi,
In my last diary, I laid out a brief overview of what Senator Edwards' job plan would cost, what it would produce, and what it would look like. In this installment, I'm going to look at some hypothetical plans for job programs, and make the case that progressives, including but not limited to Sen. Edwards, should push for a larger number of "stepping stone" jobs.

At the moment, Sen. Edwards' plan calls for the creation of one million public employment jobs. This is, of itself, a perfectly acceptable number, given the levels of cost, production, economic effect, and so forth that it would have. However, I'd like to make the case that progressives should consider increasing that number, both for policy reasons and political reasons.


First off, the policy reasons. One of the ways that public employment works in terms of producing economic results is through multiplier effects - in terms of wages, when the newly hired workers spend their wages, it tends to prompt businesses to take the extra receipts and use the money to expand their businesses with new machines/workplaces/workers and pay their workers more (theoretically); in terms of employment, when you pull newly-hired people out of the ranks of the unemployed, it decreases labor supply, which tends to push wages upward. However, in order to affect something as large as the American economy, size does matter. The larger a program, the more of an effect it will have, and there is a certain threshold below which it won't really have an effect.

So, a one million-strong would have the effect of decreasing unemployment from 6.8 million people (4.5%) to 5.8 million people (3.8%). This is historically low, comparable to the height of the economic boom in 2000. However, it's questionable whether this would have enough of an impact on wages, which have seen almost flat growth in recent years despite relatively low unemployment. It we increased the size of the public employment program to, say, three million jobs, we'd get a drop in unemployment to 3.8 million (2.5%) which is comparable to the height of the post-WWII boom, and is much more likely to produce positive wage growth.

Moreover, the effects on poverty would be much greater. As I argued in the last installment, a one million-strong jobs program could bring 2.59-3.14 million people out of poverty, which reduce poverty by 7.2-8.7%, bringing the total U.S poverty rate down to 11.1-10.9%, which be the lowest since 1972. A three million-strong program could bring 7.7-9.4 million people out of poverty, which would reduce poverty by about 20-26%, bringing the total U.S poverty rate down to 9.7%-9.2%, which would be the lowest rate ever recorded in American history. To give some transnational perspective, reducing the poverty rate to 11.1-10.9% would bring our poverty rate down to only a little more than the Netherlands; reducing the poverty rate to 9.7%-9.2% would bring our poverty rate down to somewhat less than Ireland's. These numbers do not include the effects of expanding EITC, establishing universal health care, and other anti-poverty measures.

The economic effects of a larger public employment program would be considerable. In addition to the halving of the unemployment rate, this reduction’s effect on the overall economy, and the addition of some $60 billion a year in new wages to consumption, the production of goods and services would be considerably greater. A three-million-strong public employment program would cost approximately $80 billion a year, and produce approximately $141 billion a year, for a net profit of $61 billion a year (40%). Thus, public employment, on its own, would increase economic growth by 1.3% a year. This point is worth emphasizing: the American government, by intervening directly in the economy, would increase economic growth rates by 1.3%.

I’ve given you the numbers, but let me explain what this means in terms of ideas: for the last thirty years, Democrats have often been accused of not having an ideology or a set of principles they stand for. I would argue that rather Democrats had been made to believe that the principles they stood for didn't work as policies and were politically dangerous, but that's a topic for another diary. The important thing is that many Democrats internalized two major parts of the neoconservative/neoliberal message: that the public sector is inherently inefficient and can't offer solutions (only the private sector and the free market can), and that the government is essentially incapable of creating economic change. We see these beliefs spread wide throughout the world of politics, academia, and journalism - just look at the articles that say that "presidents are blamed for the economy, but do little to affect it."

What large-scale public employment would do would show Democrats, and hopefully voters and journalists as well, that the public sector can in fact provide solutions to major problems facing Americans, and that economic policy can in fact dramatically reshape the American economy. Moreover, it's the kind of policy that ties itself right into our ideas and ideology in a simple and clear fashion: we can believe that the government works, so Democrats can go out and argue that we are the party that believes in using the government to help ordinary Americans (as opposed to the Republicans who believe in billions for the rich, but not a penny for ordinary Americans), and make the argument that Democratic economic policy can provide jobs, economic opportunity, and rising wages - and that Republican policies can't.

Public employment would be our version of cutting taxes: Republicans believe in less government, and that provides a straight path to a policy of cutting taxes, which becomes the public conception of the Republican agenda (Republicans want to cut taxes, cut spending, fight wars). For us, it would be Democrats believe in active government, so that leads to a policy of acting to provide jobs, which becomes the public conception of our agenda (Democrats want to create jobs, provide free health care, establish peace). All of the sudden, everyone (including Democrats) know what Democrats stand for.

Second, in terms of politics, one of the problems that Democrats have had in recent years is that we have tended to propose our programs at 100% of what we want to achieve, or in an effort to appear reasonable or moderate, we lower our initial offer to something closer to 50-75% of what we want to achieve, and then in the normal legislative bargaining process, we get knocked down even further. Republicans have traditionally not done this - instead, they've started at 200% of what they want or think they can achieve, and then Democrats negotiate them down to something closer to 100%, and then we congratulate ourselves for forcing them to moderate their demands.

The first Bush tax cut was a perfect example of this - the Republicans opened with an offer of $1.6 trillion dollars, which was the biggest tax cut ever, and Daschle, et al. bargained them down to $1.3 trillion and congratulated themselves for pushing them down by $300 billion when really the Bush administration had got the bulk of what they wanted.

So even if progressives only want 1 million public employment jobs, they should ask for 3, so that when they get bargained down, the end result is big enough to have the kind of impact on American poverty rates and the American economy that they hope to achieve. In general, this should also be our policy on all legislation, from health care to taxes to environmental policy - come in at 200% to get 100%.

To offer a historical parallel: one of the worst policy mistakes made by a progressive happened in 1937, when FDR decided to show that the New Deal "had worked" and was no longer needed, and so balanced the budget by drastically cutting (more or less stopping) all of the spending programs - the WPA being the most prominent. The private sector hadn't actually recovered to the point where it could do without the government pumping money into the economy, and the economy went into a recession. Roosevelt realized his mistake, and put together a budget that restored the cuts, and more or less got the economy back to where it had been in 1937 (with economic production recovered, and employment partially recovered) by 1939-40. In the mean time, FDR had lost the major pillar of his political strength - his claim to fame that his policies were actually aiding recovery. As a result, FDR lost all opportunity to push for things like the Hospital Insurance Act of 1938 (which would have provided contributory coverage for hospital visits for American workers). (And yes, the court-packing scheme did also hurt his political position; the recession, however, made a setback a catastrophe)

The morale: appearing "reasonable" isn't worth it, being victorious is.

In my next diary, I'll be discussing the difference between public employment and public works, and the importance this has for Democratic economic and social welfare policy.

[+/-] Read More...

Culture Corner: The Politics of High Fantasy

All my reading life, I've been a fan of fantasy novels. It started in grade school, where Dungeons and Dragons novels were the first adult-length novels I got my hands on in the school library.

However, in recent yesrs, I've become increasingly unable to read and enjoy traditional fantasy novels. That doesn't mean I've stopped reading fantasy altogether; I've just switched almost entirely to fantasy novels that subvert, challenge, or ignore the traditional tropes of fantasy: kings, knights, dragons, sorcerers, the whole, weighty tradition that runs from J.R.R Tolkien to Joseph Campbell's work on mythology.

Why? Because the politics of high fantasy sucks. It's usually not intentional; most fantasy writers and readers aren't really thinking about politics. But the fact of the matter is that all of those True Kings, Chivalrous Knights, Damsels in Distress, Towering Castles, and the rest of it are all based on the European Middle Ages or the Dark Ages. The source materials - La Morte d'Arthur, Beowulf, older myths of the Celtic, Scandinavian, and Germanic peoples - are all right there. And the society they are based on is one of feudalism and serfdom.

Serfdom, for those who weren't really paying attention to who the peasants fleeing the evil hordes who must be saved by Our Hero were, was the social order that emerged in Europe following the fall of the Roman Empire and lasted until, depending on which country you're talking about, well into the 19th century. Under serfdom, 90% of the population were legal property of their feudal lords, bound to work without pay for their masters, and tied to the land which they worked on. Serfdom was imposed on the common peoples of Europe by violence or the threat of violence - in the wake of the fall of the Roman Empire, farmers and former agricultural slaves were either pressed into serving the warlords who had conquered their lands, or were driven by necessity to selling themselves to the local warlords who promised protection from other rampaging warlords. While serfdom was not as uniformly oppressive as other regimes of slavery - serfdom divided peasants between "freemen," villeins," half-villeins, and other categories of greater and lesser freedoms - it's still a system of human oppression.

The True King who's been overthrown by his Evil Vizier, Scheming Relative, or the Barbarous Horde? He owns thousands if not millions of people. The noble Knight who rides to save the Fair Maiden from the Evil Dragon? His primary occupation is to kidnap people and enslave them, to put down slave rebellions with brutal violence, and to prevent other armed men from doing the same to his property. The Good Prince? Never worked a day in his life, and every crumb of bread and scrap of cloth he owns was bought with money stolen from ordinary people. This kind of thinking puts something of a damper on my enjoyment of the pleasures found within the luridly-painted covers of airport fantasy novels.

Yet in recent years, I've found myself increasing unable to stop thinking about them, because for me this history is quite real. European working class families have long historical memories, and when I was a kid, my English father told me about the history of his family. One of the stories was that one of my ancestors had been executed for rebellion against the crown. A couple of years ago, I found an actual academic source for this, in William Oren's The Great Rising of 1381:

...the two London butchers, Adam Attewell and Roger Harry, both of whom were afterwards prominent in the troubles in the capital, are said to have been raising the Essex peasantry fourteen days before they entered London, i. e. about May 31 or June i. See Essex indictments and the Sheriff's reports of Nov. ao, 1383, in R6ville, p. 196. (p. 33)


This stuck in my head, and its one of those family legends that you cherish, because it gives you a connection to some kind of past glory. But it did make me think twice about the romance of the medieval. How could I read about good Kings and noble Knights without thinking, somewhere in the back of my mind, that if I really was alive in Middle Earth or Krynn or the Forgotten Realms, that I would probably not be one of the big, muscle-bound armored men on horseback riding around Saving the Day, but rather some poor bastard chained to his plow, who works from sunup to sundown to put food into the belly of that useless hulk with the sword and shield.

It's a strange thing to think of heroes as social parasites, but there you go.

The better fantasy novels are aware of this history, and it allows me to keep on reading them. R. Scott Bakker's series about the Prince of Nothing and the Aspect-Emperor are steeped in the lore of the First Crusade, but it doesn't ever flinch from the fact that the Crusader Knights were vicious murdering fanatics, and that medieval society was based on the oppression of the peasantry. Tad William's Memory, Sorrow, and Thorn series shows its kings to be liars, madmen, and chronicles the overthrow of a corrupt tyrant. He's replaced by a "good king," which is a bit of a disappointment, but there you go. Other than these, and I'm missing out a few, I've really stopped reading medieval fantasy novels.

Instead, I've started to get really into fantasy novels set in the Renaissance or later. Unmfortunately, there aren't many of these - Mercedes Lackey, Dave Flint, and Eric Feer's Shadow of the Lion and the sequel This Rough Magic, and the various Warhammer Fantasy novels. Why do I prefer the Renaissance? First, you've got more interesting politics - in addition to kings and barons, you've got various forms of Republics, mercantile city-states, and petty princedoms, all of which gives much more scope for ordinary people to do important things. Second, you've got an explosion of knowledge, with a bubbling ferment of science, arts, literature, philosophy, history, political science, and a roster of geniuses whose human brilliance is much more appealing than the aloof other-ness of a Merlin. Third, you've got more cultural diversity - trade, intrigue, and war between Europe, the Middle East, Africa, and Asia, a world that is expanding, due to exploration and colonialism.

More modern settings, such as the "urban fantasy" of Charles De Lint, can be also very rewarding, if done with the correct tone and voice. But there's not enough of it compared to the huge mounds of standard sword-and-sorcery worlds with knights and kings, and faceless, happy peasants.

So why don't people go out and write fantasy novels that don't involve the disneyfication of serfdom?

[+/-] Read More...

Re-Post Number 2: "What Would a Modern WPA Look LIke?" (August 8, 2007)

Note:

This post comes a day later than the first, when I shifted from talking about the historical issues involved and started doing a little policy-blogging. What's interesting here from two years out or so is how the numbers for poverty and unemployment look good compared to the current day.

So below you will find some of my earliest thinking about how direct job creation would actually work:

---------------------------------------------------------------------------------

In my last diary/blog post, I talked about learning about Sen. Edwards' job plan and my own research into the historical roots of public employment.

Today, I thought I'd share a rough idea of what a modern public employment program would cost and what it would produce and what it would look like.

In my next diary, I'll talk about the potential released by a larger public employment program than the 1 million suggested by Sen. Edwards.


Note: for the purposes of full disclosure, I'm not a trained economist. If I've made an error in my statistics or my economic assumptions, please feel free to correct me.

To begin with, I'm using Senator Edwards' proposal for 1 million "stepping-stone" jobs as my baseline, as its one of the more concrete of the current presidential candidates' proposals on creating public employment jobs. Let's say for the purposes of argument that Senator Edwards' plan would create 1 million public employment jobs. If we were to offer a salary of, say $20,000/year (approx. $10.50/hr) plus health insurance, which is not a great salary but not awful either, that would provide significantly more than the minimum wage and according to the current U.S poverty line (which I know if not very accurate), just about over the poverty line for a family of four.

In terms of cost, I've worked it out that Edward's proposal would cost $20 billion a year in payroll (assuming an avg. salary of $20k/year), so figure $30 billion total a year when you throw in land, materials, overhead, and so forth (historically speaking, the WPA's total non-labor budget was approximately 20% of the total; here, I've estimated 30% to be on the safe side). In budgetary terms, that's extremely doable without affecting the deficit to a degree that causes significant inflation.

In terms of the impact on American society, those one million jobs created, assuming an average household/family size between 2.59-3.14 (the difference is largely due to counting single households), could bring 2.59-3.14 million people out of poverty, which reduce poverty by 7.2-8.7%, bringing the total U.S poverty rate down to 11.1-10.9%, which be the lowest since 1972. This in in and of itself would be a major social and economic policy accomplishment, probably one of the greatest in the last thirty years.

In terms of what you could do with those jobs, quite a lot. The roughly two-million-worker-strong WPA's building program over the eight years of its operation included the construction of 116,000 buildings, 78,000 bridges, and 651,000 miles (1,047,000 km) of roads and the improvement of 800 airports. That works out to what, 14.5 thousand buildings, 9.75 thousand bridges, 81 thousand miles of road, and 100 airports a year? Keep in mind, that's with 1930's levels of productivity, skills, and technology.

With modern productivity, even assuming that the unemployed people who are hired have half the average productivity of the American worker (the average American worker produces approx. $90,000 a year in goods and services), we'd still produce public goods and services to the tune of $47,000/year per worker, for a grand total of $47 billion produced per year. Deducting the cost of running the program, and you're still adding $17 billion to the economy that wasn't there before (a net profit of approx. 30%)- just in untapped labor power.

As to what this program would look like, I'd point you back in the direction of the public employment programs of the New Deal. When the New Deal established public employment programs, they created a kind of "movement culture" that resembled that of the new unions. Workers on public employment programs showed a huge rebound of morale after dispiriting years after years on the unemployment line - famously, one woman told a reporter "my family isn't on charity. My husband, he works for the government."

People who worked for the CWA and later the WPA founded their own newspapers where they described themselves as an "army of the unemployed" who would "slay the dragon of the Great Depression through work." In New York City, for example, the administrator of the CWA (Civil Works Administration) was so dedicated to his work of providing jobs for some 250,000 people, that he actually worked himself to death in the winter of 1933. The New York City's CWA TIMES printed a banner headline "KILLED IN ACTION" and compared the administrator to Leonidas of the 300 Spartans at Thermopylae.

Workers in the CWA and WPA formed the Worker's Alliance, a union of the publicly-employed, who marched in the streets on behalf of their program and their work. In my research into these programs, I came across an envelope in the CWA correspondence archives in the FDR library in Hyde Park, which was filled with photos that workers on a CWA project in Pennsylvania had sent President Roosevelt of themselves building the stone wall of a library as a thank-you present for giving them jobs, and the look in the faces of these men, wearing fedoras and collared shirts to look their best even as they posed with wheelbarrows of bricks and trowels and hammers in hand, was one of great pride and joy, and a real sense of comradeship.

More on the potential of a larger public employment program in my next diary.

[+/-] Read More...

Sunday, March 29, 2009

Re-Post Number 1: " The WPA and Sen. Edwards' Million Jobs - Historical Legacies of the New Deal" (Tue Aug 07, 2007)

Note:
As part of a collection effort, I present the first in a series of posts formerly written as diaries on DailyKos, all focused on the theme of public employment policy. Each post will be preceded by a short comment explaining the context of the original piece.

In this first case, "The WPA and Sen. Edwards' Million Jobs," dates back to mid-May 2007, when I was first getting interested in the candidates for the 2008 presidential election. I had been feeling much more positive about politics since the 2006 midterms, when Democrats had taken over the Congress, and was starting to look around at who I would support.

Keep in mind that this was back during the days in which Barack Obama was a little-known politician, who I mostly knew for giving a good speech at the 2004 National Convention and beating the tar out of Alan Keyes in a race for the U.S Senate. Hillary Clinton was the odds-on favorite to win the nomination, and I knew I didn't want her as the party's nominee. As a New Yorker who had seen her 2000 campaign and her subsequent political shift to the right, I didn't think that Hillary could be the kind of unapologetically progressive candidate I was looking for. Obama, at that time, was still in the proecess of molding his platform, his argument, and his strategy, and was still in the more extreme phase of his "post-partisan" stance. This didn't really appeal to me.

Instead, I was interested in Senator John Edwards. I hadn't really liked him in 2004 - I supported Howard Dean - because of his then pro-war stance, but I had liked his "two Americas" rhetoric, and had preferred him against Kerry. However, it was his public policy positions in 2007-8 that got me to support him.

So here's the first post to be brought back into the light, warts and all:

Hi,

This is based on a blog entry I made on Edwards' blog in May, that I thought I'd repost here to add to the discussion of the WPA [ed - Works Progress Administration] going on in other blog/diaries. Just to introduce myself, I'm a graduate student in the history of public policy writing a dissertation on the history of public employment in the United States, with a central focus on the WPA.


Anyway, back in March, I had been an Edwards supporter for a while, but I was motivated to post about this on his blog when, challenged by some friends of mine on an email-listserv (I know, very quaint), I was asked to detail Sen. Edwards' poverty plan. Somewhat chagrined that I didn't know the details off the top of my head, I went back to his site and checked it out. (This was back when the plan was relatively new, before the tour and so forth).

Imagine my total surprise when I found that one of the first items on the page was the creation of 1 million temporary jobs for the unemployed. You see, my research subject, the topic I'm writing my dissertation on, is the history of public employment in the United States, beginning with the creation of the Civil Works Administration in 1933 through to the demise of CETA in the late 70's-early 80's.

As both a scholar and an activist, I have in my day-to-day life been making in the case that public employment - the direct hiring of the unemployed by the government to reduce unemployment and produce useful public goods and services - was the heart and soul of the New Deal in its day (Social Security being the most lasting and most important part since then), that it was the distinctively American approach to the welfare state, and that it was a truly successful program that should be the cornerstone of the Democratic Party's politics and policy, but was buried due to racial prejudice, fears of Communism, and business' desire for a monopoly on labor.

Indeed, I had just finished my first major piece of research on this topic, a study of the Committee on Economic Security (the committee that drafted the Social Security Act of 1935) arguing that public employment was the major competitor to the limited system social-insurance that was proposed, that it was a much more sweeping, inclusive, and original intellectual development, and that it was seen by the Committee as the critical policy that would extend the New Deal to all Americans (including women and blacks), fill in the gaps in the safety net, and ensure the fiscal wellbeing of the system, while preventing dependency and promoting work.

What I found in my study of the CES' archives was that many of the members of the committee had been officials from Harry Hopkins' Federal Emergency Relief Administration, veterans of the Civil Works Administration (a precursor to the WPA that employed 4.2 million people from the winter of 1933 through the spring of 1934), and were all advocates of public employment. These officials pushed for a vision of a social welfare state in which jobs, not welfare or unemployment insurance, would be the lynch-pin of protection against poverty. Essentially, any American who was without work or who had lost their job would have the right to apply for a public employment job.

Not only would this job stave off poverty by providing wages to the worker and their family, but it would also help to reinforce the Social Security system by keeping the drain on Unemployment Insurance low or preventing the need for it altogether, by ensuring that the newly-employed worker would continue contributing to Social Security (thus maximizing the in-flow to the Social Security coffers), and by ensuring that Americans "not normally eligible" for social insurance would build up participation in the system (namely domestic workers and agricultural workers, the majority of women and African-Americans in the work-force). Finally, the idea was that public employment would provide political cover for the rest of the Social Security program by emphasizing that FDR's new system would emphasize work over "the dole."

Moreover, the FERA advocates argued that the public employment program alone would act as both social welfare and economic policy. Public employment would directly reduce unemployment, boost the purchasing power of the average American and therefore consumption of goods, and set off a positive-multiplier effect throughout the economy at large. Thus, whereas social insurance would act to deflate the economy, public employment would re-inflate the economy and promote economic recovery. Moreover, public employment would serve to re-distribute wealth from the richest tax-payers to ordinary workers. But most importantly, public employment would do so in a way that returned value to the tax-payer - public employment workers would provide labor in exchange for wages, producing goods and services that would offset the cost of the program and increase economic growth, while improving the national infrastructure.

Little known today, the final Social Security report recommended public employment as the "first objective of reform." A public employment bill appropriating $4 billion dollars for the program was introduced nearly simultaneously to the Social Security bill, and was passed at about the same time. Yet today, few associate public employment with the achievements of the New Deal, let alone with Social Security.

[+/-] Read More...

Blog Launch, Activate!

After many years of non-blogging, diarying/commenting on other people's blogs, and other online miscellanea, I've decided to set up this blog as a way of placing all the stuff I've written, am writing, and will write in one place.

Forthcoming regular series:

  1. Re-Posting of Past Writings on History, Public Policy and Politics
  2. Regular Roundups on Public Employment and Public Works Policy
  3. Periodic Obama Administration Policy Analysis - Possibly as monthly series?
  4. Random Historical Personality of the Week/Month
  5. This Date In History

[+/-] Read More...